From Daily Mirror
The Sri Lankan Central
Bank’s issue of a 30-year bond on February 27, 2015 ran into immediate
controversy. The main reason was that markets were expecting the bank to take
up only around Rs.1 billion, but the bank accepted bids upwards of Rs.10 billion.
The weighted average rate of return paid on the bond was also driven up by the
excess uptake (the term ‘interest rate’ will be used for this, instead of
‘yield’, for reader simplicity).
The public outcry that
has followed this unexpected move by the Central Bank comprised two concerns.
One is the high uptake at a high interest rate. The second is that the largest
beneficiary of the issue was a company that is closely connected to the sitting
governor of the Central Bank – creating a serious conflict of interest for the
governor’s involvement in any decisions on the bids. The political and
bureaucratic establishments of Sri Lanka have very poor rules and controls with
regard to managing conflicts of interest, which have over time become rampant.
Public focus on this problem is hence a positive development.
The first aspect of
the problem- of a high uptake at a high interest rate- has led to a series of
articles in newspapers that have attempted to calculate the ‘loss’ that has
resulted from the high rate. That the question has been asked and many
contributions made, including by the ex-governor of the Central Bank, is again
a positive development. Unfortunately, the contributions published to date
suffer from a combination of three problems: (1) a computational error on the
time-value of money, (2) an inaccurate stipulation of the base-rate and (3) a
weak assumption with regard to market impact and ‘loss’.
Computational
error on time-value of money
This error was first
highlighted by an article published in the Sri Lankan FT by Dr. Udara Peiris,
now a tenured professor of finance at the National Research University Higher
School of Economics, Moscow, Russia (for that article see http://www.ft.lk/2015/04/29/a-clarification-on-the-cost-of-the-bond-scandal/).
The error made is the
failure to recognise that trying to add future money to present money is like
adding apples and oranges. All money that is added up to calculate loss must
first be computed to its value at a specific time and the loss should be stated
in terms of the loss at that time. If a person lost Rs.1,000 today and the
interest rates are 10.4 percent, it is the same as losing Rs.2,000 seven years
later, or Rs.4,000, 14 years later (money doubles every seven years when kept
at a compounded annual interest rate of 10.4 percent). Therefore, losing
Rs.1,000 today and losing Rs.4,000 14 years later is not the same as losing
Rs.5,000 today. It is only the same as losing Rs.2,000 today.
The time-value of
money is a basic and core principle of financial calculations and the press
articles, apart from Dr. Peiris’, seem to have ignored it. The result has been
erroneous calculations that add up money due in 20 and 30 years with money due
in the present year, without discounting future payments to the present value.
The result is incorrect calculations that hugely exaggerate the loss.
Inaccurate
stipulation of base-rate
All calculations of
loss are based on estimating the ‘extra’ interest that was paid for the 30-year
bond, above and beyond some base-rate – that is, the expected rate had the bond
issue not been controversially increased by a multiple of 10 times.
Various rates are used
by writers, all of them well under 10 percent - some based on signals given by
the Central Bank before the issue, others based on similar bond issues in the
past and yet others based on trading and yields in the secondary market.
However, such speculation is not necessary, as the actual bids are known.
A Public Debt
Department (PDD) document, leaked to the public domain through the Internet (in
a positive act of whistle-blowing), provides details of all the bids accepted
and this has over time received significant circulation. The document shows
that the market was not offering the Central Bank the low rates that the bank
signalled, based on secondary market trading and past rates on tap issues of
the bank. If bids were not prorated, clearing the Rs.1 billion mark would have
meant accepting Rs.1.308 billion (including a full Rs.0.5 billion from the
EPF). The average weighted return paid out then would have been 10.465
percent.
The leaks to the press
from the draft COPE report say that the PDD recommended taking bids up to
Rs.2.608 billion. The recommendation does not ring an alarm as Rs.2.358
billion of this total came from government-controlled entities – Rs.1.5 billion
from the EPF and the rest from government banks and none (even by proxy) from
Perpetual Treasuries, which has been identified as the dubious bidder where the
governor has a conflict of interest. Even though the PDD recommended more than
double the uptake of what was announced (which is not a good practice), such
deviation – taking multiples of two to three times – had also been a regular
practice in the past years (mostly on shorter tenure bonds) and did not risk spooking
the markets.
The weighted rate for
the Rs.2.608 billion uptake was 10.724 percent (PDD calculations). This then
provides the actual base rate that needs no guess work – it is based on the
actual bids received and the PDD recommended uptake. Calculations hitherto
published have not used this information and therefore have not been able to
set the appropriate base rate.
“Loss”: In deviating from initial PDD
recommendation
The final uptake of
Rs.10.058 billion came at a rate of 11.727 percent. The loss calculation
therefore would be the difference between this rate and the rate for Rs.2.608
billion. The excess interest paid in increasing the uptake was therefore 1
percent (or 1.003 percent to be precise). The present value of the loss for
over 30 years, in taking Rs.10.058 billion at this higher rate, rather than the
lower base rate is equal to almost Rs.0.9 billion (896,430,491 to be precise).
This is a large loss. However, it is also only a fraction of the Rs.8.7 billion
loss erroneously calculated on this 30-year bond by, for instance, the
ex-governor of the Central Bank. Of the Rs.7.8 billion difference, Rs.5.7
billion comes from the computational error and Rs.2.1 billion from speculating
a different base-rate.
Flawed
assumption on market impact/“loss”
The lion share of the
losses calculated by contributors is not on the 30-year bond, but on subsequent
bonds sold in the market, attributing their higher interest rates as a
spill-over impact. It is assumed that the increased rate on subsequent bond
sales is the impact and loss of surprising the market on the 30-year bond. This
is a flawed assumption for three reasons (as noted by Dr. Peiris as well). (A)
Fluctuations of government interest rates cannot be interpreted simplistically
as profit and loss to the government, when the interest rates are managed by
the government for various purposes – to influence savings and consumption, to
handle liquidity issues and to manage exchange rates. (B) Interest rates are a
‘price’ for borrowing driven by supply and demand – increasing borrowing demand
increases prices (interest rates) and such changes in pricing have various
balancing consequences.
For instance, shifting
from international borrowing towards local borrowing (as has happened in the
first half of 2015) increases the government’s demand for local debt and will
tend to increase interest rates, while protecting against future external debt
pressures. (C) Local economic factors, private sector borrowing picking up and
reduced excess liquidity in the banking sector (another feature of 2015) also
put upward pressure on interest rates.
Overall, the 10 times
increase in the uptake of the 30-year bond did surprise the markets and
increased the rate by at least 1 percent over where expectations could have
been set. Furthermore, the spill-over effects could be stipulated to have
impacted rates on further government borrowing in the immediate after-math. But
this cannot be used to explain much of the increase in borrowing rates (the
market bids themselves, without the 10 times multiple, already signalled an
increased rate for the 30-year bond). In any case, the forced impact on
interest rates is small, as the government can always reject bids if it does
not fit with its own expectations of where the rates should be and because the
government has huge captive funds through the EPF and its banks, which are in
any case the major borrowers at the higher rates. Furthermore, if the
government is lending to itself (or to the EPF funds of workers) at a higher
rate of interest, it is not accurate to describe this as a “loss”.
Largest loss
is trust
If the government
needed more funds, expanding borrowing on a rarely auctioned 30-year bond, that
has the added function of price-discovery, was not the appropriate route.
Building stability and
confidence are primary responsibilities of central banking. Spooking the
markets and creating uncertainty by spiking the uptake on the 30-year bond
auction cannot be credited as a responsible action.
While calculations of
the resulting monetary loss have been erroneous and hugely exaggerated, the
biggest loss is probably not monetary; it is the loss of trust and confidence.
Sri Lanka’s Central Bank has seen an erosion of trust for some time and the
advent of a new government and governor created an opportunity to repair and
restore trust. But the 30 year bond debacle, coupled with the weakness of
investigations and accountability, has set back the Central Bank.
(Verité Research is an
independent think-tank based in Colombo that provides strategic analysis to
high level decision-makers in economics, law, politics and media. Comments are
welcome. Email publications@veriteresearch.org)
No comments:
Post a Comment